summaryrefslogtreecommitdiff
path: root/saved-articles/to have is to owe.txt
diff options
context:
space:
mode:
Diffstat (limited to 'saved-articles/to have is to owe.txt')
-rwxr-xr-xsaved-articles/to have is to owe.txt603
1 files changed, 603 insertions, 0 deletions
diff --git a/saved-articles/to have is to owe.txt b/saved-articles/to have is to owe.txt
new file mode 100755
index 0000000..0444abf
--- /dev/null
+++ b/saved-articles/to have is to owe.txt
@@ -0,0 +1,603 @@
+---
+title: To Have Is to Owe
+Triple Canopy
+date: 2010-12-09T23:17:44Z
+source: http://canopycanopycanopy.com/10/to_have_is_to_owe
+tags: finance, money
+
+---
+
+Mesopotamian usury, Vedic accounting, American Jubilee: excavating the
+history of fiscal debt. Illustrations by [Joanna
+Neborsky](/contributors#neborsky_joanna).
+
+“To Have Is to Owe” contains excerpts from David Graeber’s forthcoming
+book [*Debt: The First 5,000
+Years*](http://www.amazon.com/Debt-First-5-000-Years/dp/1933633867/ref=sr_1_1?ie=UTF8&s=books&qid=1291747069&sr=8-1),
+to be published by Melville House in January 2011. It was produced by
+Triple Canopy as part of its [Research
+Work](/projectareas#project_areas) project area, supported in part by
+the New York Council for the Humanities and the Brown Foundation, Inc.
+of Houston.
+
+Payment Due
+-----------
+
+For thousands of years, the struggle between rich and poor has largely
+taken the form of conflicts between creditors and debtors—of arguments
+about the rights and wrongs of interest payments, debt peonage, amnesty,
+repossession, restitution, the sequestering of sheep, the seizing of
+vineyards, and the selling of debtors’ children into slavery. By the
+same token, for the past five thousand years, with remarkable
+regularity, popular insurrections have begun the same way: with the
+ritual destruction of debt records—tablets, papyri, ledgers; whatever
+form they might have taken in any particular time and place. In the
+throes of the recent economic crisis, with the very defining
+institutions of capitalism crumbling, surveys showed that an
+overwhelming majority of Americans felt that the country’s banks should
+not be rescued—*whatever the economic consequences*—but that ordinary
+citizens stuck with bad mortgages should be bailed out. This is quite
+extraordinary, as Americans have, since colonial days, been the
+population least sympathetic to debtors. (Back then, the ears of an
+insolvent debtor would often be nailed to a post.) The notion of
+morality as a matter of paying one’s debts runs deeper in the United
+States than in almost any other country, which is odd, since America was
+settled largely by absconding debtors. Despite the
+
+fact that the Constitution specifically charged the new government with
+creating a bankruptcy law in 1787, all attempts to do so were rejected
+on “moral grounds” until 1898, by which time almost all other Western
+states had adopted one. The change was epochal.[1](#)
+
+Those charged with moderating political debate in our media and
+legislatures have decided that this is not the time for another such
+change. The US government effectively put a three-trillion-dollar
+band-aid over the problem, changing nothing. Financiers were “bailed out
+with taxpayer money”—in other words, their imaginary money was treated
+as if it were real—while mortgage holders were mostly left to the tender
+mercy of the courts, subjected to a bankruptcy law that, the previous
+year, Congress had made far more exacting against debtors. We have even
+seen a backlash against small-scale debtors, one driven by financial
+corporations that have now turned to the same government that bailed
+them out to apply the full force of the law against ordinary citizens in
+financial trouble. “It’s not a crime to owe money,” reports the
+*Minneapolis Star-Tribune*. “But people are routinely being thrown in
+jail for failing to pay debts.” In Minnesota, “the use of arrest
+warrants against
+
+1 The nature of money has always been particularly contentious in the
+US, as evidenced by the endless battles between goldbugs, greenbackers,
+free bankers, bimetallists, and silverites in the nineteenth century.
+American voters were so suspicious of the very idea of central banks
+that the Federal Reserve system was created only on the eve of World War
+I, three centuries after the Bank of England was founded. Even the
+monetization of the national debt was seen by Thomas Jefferson as a
+pernicious alliance between warriors and financiers, though it opened
+the way to government assuming the role of moral debtor, and of freedom
+being perceived as something literally owed to the nation.
+
+Aristocratic debtors were wined and dined by liveried servants and
+allowed to receive prostitutes. Impoverished inmates were shackled
+together in tiny cells, where they “suffered to die, without pity, of
+hunger and jail fever.”
+
+debtors has jumped 60 percent over the past four years, with 845 cases
+in 2009. In Illinois and southwest Indiana, some judges jail debtors for
+missing court-ordered debt payments. In extreme cases, people stay in
+jail until they raise a minimum payment. In January [2010], a judge
+sentenced a Kenney, Ill., man ‘to indefinite incarceration’ until he
+came up with \$300 toward a lumber yard debt.”[2](#)
+
+Despite all this, we hardly know what debt is. The very flexibility of
+the concept is the basis of its power, and of the moral confusion
+associated with it. Looking at the history of debt worldwide, one
+
+2 Throughout history, certain sorts of debts, and certain sorts of
+debtors, have been treated differently from others. The British public
+was scandalized in the 1720s when the popular press exposed the fact
+that debtors’ prisons were regularly divided into two sections.
+Aristocratic inmates, who often thought of a brief stay in Fleet or
+Marshelsea as something of a fashion statement, were wined and dined by
+liveried servants and allowed to receive regular visits from
+prostitutes. On the “common side,” impoverished debtors were shackled
+together in tiny cells, “covered with filth and vermin,” as one report
+put it, “and suffered to die, without pity, of hunger and jail fever.”
+
+finds that most people have held that paying back money one has borrowed
+is a simple matter of morality and, contradictorily, that anyone in the
+habit of lending money is evil. Recently, the former position seems to
+have trumped the latter, owing to a persistent refusal to question our
+slavish devotion to creditors. But if the welfare state must be
+destroyed in order, ostensibly, to settle our debts, we should ask
+ourselves: To whom, exactly, are those debts owed? And where did our
+creditors get the money that was loaned to us? (The answer, of course:
+We owe the very financial institutions we recently bailed out for making
+fraudulent and idiotic loans; they didn’t *get* the money anywhere, they
+just
+
+made it up.) Whenever such questions have been openly asked in Europe,
+riots have tended to ensue.
+
+Such eruptions make it clear that debt must be removed from that
+rarefied sphere of morality arbitrated by transnational institutions
+(whose representatives are also its main beneficiaries), where it has
+become ensconced, and returned to the sphere of open political debate.
+In the ancient world, it was not debt that was considered sacred, but
+rather the power to make it disappear. We are, it seems, long overdue
+for a contemporary Jubilee, one that would affect consumer debt as well
+as international debt, and that would not only relieve a great amount of
+human suffering but also remind us that money is not ineffable, that
+paying one’s debt is not the essence of morality, that borrowing and
+lending are human arrangements, and that if
+
+democracy is to mean anything, it is the ability to all agree to arrange
+things differently.
+
+It is significant that, since Hammurabi, great imperial states have
+invariably resisted this kind of
+
+politics. Athens and Rome established the paradigm: Even when confronted
+with continual debt crises, they insisted on legislating around the
+edges, softening the impact; they eliminated obvious abuses like debt
+slavery and used the spoils of empire to throw all sorts of extra
+benefits at their poorer citizens (who, after all, provided the rank and
+file of their armies) so as to keep them afloat. They did all this in
+such a way as to fend off any challenge to the principle of debt itself.
+The US has taken a remarkably similar approach: eliminating the worst
+abuses (e.g., debtors’ prisons), using the fruits of empire to provide
+subsidies, visible and otherwise, and, recently, manipulating currency
+rates to flood the country with cheap goods from China. Never has the
+governing class allowed anyone to question the sacred principle that we
+all must pay our debts. That principle has recently been exposed to be a
+flagrant lie. As it turns out, we *all* don’t have to pay our debts.
+Only some of us do.
+
+**Mesopotamia, 2400 BCE**\
+ Usury was common practice by 2400 BCE. Officials or merchants advanced
+loans to peasants and, if they were unable to pay, began to appropriate
+their possessions, starting with grain, goats, and
+
+furniture, then moving on to fields and houses, then family members.
+First went the servants, followed by children, wives, and even the
+borrower himself, all of whom were reduced to debt peons until the money
+was repaid. This threatened to rip society apart: If for any reason
+there was a bad harvest, large proportions of the peasantry fell into
+debt peonage. Indebted farmers in fear of repossession abandoned their
+fields.
+
+Faced with the potential for complete social breakdown, Sumerian and
+Babylonian kings periodically announced general amnesties. All
+outstanding consumer debt was declared null and void (commercial debts
+were not affected), all land was returned to its original owners, and
+debt peons were returned to their families. Before long, kings made a
+habit of declaring such amnesties upon assuming power. (The sovereign
+saw himself as literally re-creating human society, so he was in a fine
+position to relieve all previous moral obligations.) In Sumerian, these
+were called declarations of freedom. The Sumerian word *amargi* is the
+first recorded use of “freedom” in any language; it literally means
+“return to mother,” since this is what freed debt peons were allowed to
+do.
+
+The Fabled Land of Barter
+-------------------------
+
+When economists speak of the origins of money, debt is always something
+of an afterthought. First comes barter, then money; credit develops only
+later. Even if one consults books on the history of money in, say,
+France, India, or China, what one generally gets is a history of
+coinage, with barely any discussion of credit arrangements at all. For
+almost a century, anthropologists like myself have been pointing out
+that there is something very wrong with this picture. Credit system,
+tabs, and even expense accounts existed long before cash. These things
+are as old as civilization itself. History tends to move back and forth
+between periods dominated by bullion, when it’s assumed that gold and
+silver *are* money, and periods in which money is assumed to be an
+abstraction, a virtual unit of account. The standard version of this
+history has little to do with how economic life is actually conducted in
+real communities and marketplaces, where everyone is likely in debt to
+everyone else in a dozen different ways, and most transactions take
+place without the use of currency.
+
+Some of it is just the nature of the evidence: Coins are preserved in
+the archaeological record, credit arrangements usually are not. Still,
+the problem runs
+
+Missionaries, adventurers, and colonial administrators fanned out across
+the world, carrying copies of *The Wealth of Nations*, expecting to find
+the land of barter. None ever did.
+
+deeper. The existence of credit and debt has always been something of a
+scandal for economists, since it’s almost impossible to pretend that
+those lending and borrowing money are acting on purely “economic”
+motivations (for instance, that a loan to a stranger is the same as a
+loan to one’s cousin). Therefore, they begin the story of money in an
+imaginary world from which credit and debt have been entirely erased:
+“Once upon a time, there was barter. It was difficult. So people
+invented money. Then came the development of banking and credit.” The
+logical, inexorable progression of humanity
+
+from Stone Age barterers of mastodon tusks to wielders of complex
+financial instruments has become common sense.
+
+We now know from ancient Egyptian and Mesopotamian records—discovered
+after Adam Smith, for whom economic history began with Homer—that credit
+systems (what is today called virtual money) preceded the invention of
+coinage by thousands of years. Money was actually created by bureaucrats
+to track state resources and spread unevenly, never completely replacing
+credit systems. Barter, in turn, is largely an accidental byproduct of
+the use of coinage or paper money, a refuge for people operating in cash
+economies where currency has for some reason become inaccessible.
+Nevertheless, nearly every introductory economics textbook in use today
+takes the same approach: “To see that society benefits
+
+from a medium of exchange, imagine a barter economy,” write Begg,
+Fischer, and Dornbuch in *Economics* (2005). “Imagine the difficulty you
+would have today if you had to exchange your labor directly for the
+fruits of someone else’s labor,” write Maunder, Myers, Wall, and Miller
+in *Economics Explained* (1991). “Imagine you have roosters, but you
+want roses,” write Parkin and King in *Economics* (1995). “One can
+imagine an old-style farmer bartering with the blacksmith, the tailor,
+the grocer, and the doctor in his small town,” write Stiglitz and
+Driffill in *Economics* (2000).
+
+There is a simple reason why everyone who writes an economics textbook
+feels the need to tell us the same story. For economists, it is in a
+very real sense the most important story ever told. It was by telling it
+in 1776 that Adam Smith, professor of moral philosophy at the University
+of Edinburgh,
+
+effectively brought the discipline of economics into being. He objected
+to the notion that money was a creation of government, and insisted that
+property, currency, and markets not only existed before political
+institutions but also were the very foundation of human society. It
+followed that insofar as government should play any role in monetary
+affairs, it should limit itself to guaranteeing the soundness of
+currency. It was only by making such an argument that he could insist
+that economics was itself a field of human inquiry with its own
+principles and laws—as distinct from, say, ethics or politics. The
+economy, in his formulation, operates
+
+by rules of its own that are separate from moral and political life; it
+is where we indulge in our natural propensity to truck and barter. We
+are still trucking and bartering, and always will be. Money is simply
+the most efficient means.
+
+For centuries, economists have searched for the fabled land of barter.
+Smith set his story in aboriginal North America, and its lack of realism
+reflects the dearth of reliable information on Native American economic
+systems in Scottish libraries. But by the middle of the nineteenth
+century, Lewis Henry Morgan’s descriptions of the Six Nations of the
+Iroquois had been published and read widely; they made clear that the
+Iroquois’s goods were stockpiled in longhouses, then allocated by
+women’s councils, without anyone ever trading arrowheads for slabs of
+meat. Economists ignored this information. Stanley Jevons, for example,
+wrote *The Principles of Political Economy*, his classic study of the
+origins of money, in 1871. He took his examples straight from Smith,
+describing Indians swapping venison for elk and beaver hides. Around the
+same time, missionaries, adventurers, and colonial administrators were
+fanning out across the world, many carrying copies of Smith’s *The
+Wealth of Nations*, expecting to find the land of barter.
+
+None ever did. They discovered an almost endless variety of economic
+systems. But to this day, no one has been able to locate a place where
+the ordinary mode of economic transaction between neighbors takes the
+form of “I’ll give you twenty chickens for that cow.”[3](#)
+
+**Madagascar, 1990** \
+ In the town of Arivonimamo, Madagascar, I had the privilege of
+interviewing a Kalanoro, a tiny, ghostly creature that a local spirit
+medium claimed to keep hidden away in a chest in his home. The spirit
+belonged to the brother of a notorious loan shark, a horrible woman
+named Nordine. I was a bit reluctant to have anything to do with the
+family, but some of my friends insisted; this was, after all, a creature
+from ancient times. The creature spoke from behind a screen, in an
+eerie, otherworldly quaver. But all it was really interested in talking
+about was money. Finally, slightly exasperated by the whole charade, I
+asked, “What did you use for money back in ancient times, when you were
+still alive?”
+
+The mysterious voice immediately replied, “We didn’t use money. In
+ancient times we used to
+
+3 This hardly means that barter does not exist—or even that it’s never
+practiced by the sort of people that Smith referred to as savages. It
+just means that it’s almost never employed between fellow villagers, as
+Smith imagined it to be.
+
+barter commodities directly, one for the other.”
+
+We all owe an infinite debt to humanity, nature, or the cosmos (however
+one prefers to frame it), but no one else can possibly tell us how to
+pay it.
+
+IOU All
+-------
+
+What gave early nation-states the right to levy taxes? Nowadays, we all
+think we know the answer to this question. We pay our taxes so that the
+government can provide us with services, starting with military
+protection. The arrangement is said to go back to an original social
+contract, though no one really knows when it was made or by whom, or why
+we should be bound by the decisions of distant ancestors on this one
+matter when we aren’t by their decisions otherwise.
+
+An alternative explanation is primordial-debt theory, a school of
+thought developed largely in France by economists, anthropologists,
+historians, and classicists; its foundational text is Michel Aglietta
+and André Orléan’s *La Violence de la Monnaie* (1992). Adherents insist
+that monetary policy cannot be separated from social policy, that the
+two have always been intertwined. Governments use taxes to create money,
+which they are able to do because
+
+they have become the guardians of the debt that all citizens have to one
+another. This debt is the essence of society itself.
+
+At first, the argument goes, this sense of debt was expressed not
+through the state, but through religion. The hymns, prayers, and poetry
+collected in the Vedas and the Brahmanas, the foundations of Hindu
+thought, constitute the earliest-known reflections on the nature of
+debt, which they treat as synonymous with guilt and sin. According to
+the commentators of the Brahmanas, human existence is itself a form of
+debt: A man, being born, is a debt; he is born to death, and only by way
+of sacrifice does he redeem himself from death. Two famous passages in
+the Brahmanas insist that we are born as a debt not just to the gods (to
+be repaid in sacrifice) but also to the sages who created the Vedic
+learning (to be repaid through study), to our ancestors (to be repaid by
+having children), and, finally, to the whole of humanity (to be repaid
+with
+
+hospitality to strangers).
+
+The first explicit theory of the debt owed by each living person to the
+society that makes his or her existence possible was formulated by
+Auguste Comte in his last work, *The Catechism of Positive Religion*
+(1852), in the form of a lecture on what came to be known as primordial,
+existential, or social debt, delivered by the priest of an imaginary
+Religion of Society. Asked for his view on human rights, the priest
+scoffs at the very notion. It is nonsense, he says, an error born of
+individualism. Positivism understands only duties. After all,
+
+> We are born under a load of obligations of every kind, to our
+> predecessors, to our successors, to our contemporaries. After our
+> birth these obligations increase or accumulate before the point where
+> we are capable of rendering anyone any service. On what human
+> foundation, then, could one seat the idea of “rights”?
+
+Comte doesn’t use the word *debt*, but it is clear what he means: We
+have already accumulated endless debts before we get to the age at which
+we can even think of paying them. And by that time there’s no way even
+to calculate to whom we owe them. The only way to redeem ourselves is to
+be dedicated to the service of humanity.
+
+Comte’s notion of an unlimited obligation to society
+
+crystallized in the notion of social debt, which was taken up among
+social reformers and, eventually, socialist politicians in many parts of
+Europe and abroad. In France the notion of a social debt soon became
+something of a catchphrase, a slogan—and, eventually, a cliché: “We are
+all born as debtors to society.” The state, according to this
+
+view, was merely the administrator of the existential debt that everyone
+owes to everyone.
+
+Theories of existential debt always end up justifying—or laying claim
+to—structures of authority. What we really have in the idea of
+primordial debt is the ultimate nationalist myth. Once we owed our lives
+to
+
+the gods who created us, paid them interest in the form of animal
+sacrifice, and, ultimately, paid back the principal with our lives. Now
+we owe our lives to the nation that formed us, pay interest in the form
+of taxes, and, when it comes time to defend the nation against its
+enemies, pay back the principal with our lives. This is a great trap of
+the twentieth century: On the one side is the logic of the market, which
+insists that we don’t owe one another anything. On the other is the
+logic of the state, which insists that we are born with a debt we can
+never truly pay. In fact, the dichotomy is false. States created
+markets, markets require states, and neither could continue without the
+other.
+
+The true ethos of our individualistic society may be found in this
+equation: We all owe an infinite debt to humanity, nature, or the cosmos
+(however one prefers to frame it), but no one else can possibly tell us
+how to pay it. All systems of established authority—religion, morality,
+politics, economics, the criminal-justice system—are revealed to be
+fraudulent ways of calculating what cannot be calculated. Freedom, then,
+is the ability to decide for ourselves how to pay our debts.
+
+\
+\
+****
+
+**England, twelfth century CE**\
+ One of the most important forms of currency during the reign of King
+Henry I was the notched “tally stick” used to record debts. Each party
+to a transaction would take a twig, notch it to indicate the amount
+owed, then split it in half. The creditor would keep one half, called
+the “stock” (hence the origin of the term “stock holder”) and the debtor
+would keep the other, called the “stub” (hence “ticket stub”). Tax
+assessors used such twigs to calculate amounts owed by local sheriffs.
+Often, though, rather than wait for the taxes to come due, Henry’s
+exchequer would sell the tallies at a discount, and they would circulate
+as tokens of debt owed to the government. The king also issued tallies
+in lieu of payment to soldiers, farmers, and others owed money by the
+state; these, too, were sold at a discount and circulated among stock
+holders.
+
+There is one puzzling aspect of this equation: The IOU can operate as
+money only as long as Henry never pays his debt. This is precisely the
+logic on which the Bank of England—the first modern central bank—was
+founded. In 1694, with public finances weak and the state's monetary and
+credit systems precarious, a consortium of English
+
+bankers made a loan of £1.2 million to King William III. In return they
+received a royal monopoly on the issuance of banknotes. Practically,
+this meant the bankers had the right to advance IOUs representing a
+portion of the king’s debt to any inhabitant of the kingdom willing to
+borrow from them, or willing to deposit his own money in the bank. The
+effect was to monetize the royal debt. This was a great deal for the
+bankers, who charged the king 8 percent annual interest on the original
+loan and, simultaneously, charged clients who borrowed money interest on
+that same debt. But the arrangement could only work for as long as the
+original loan remained outstanding. Which is why, to this day, the loan
+has never been paid back. It cannot be. If it ever were, the entire
+monetary system of the United Kingdom would cease to exist.
+
+God’s Money
+-----------
+
+In today’s world, paying one’s debts can seem the very definition of
+morality, if only because so many fail to do it. When faced with a debt,
+large corporations and even some small businesses will almost
+automatically wait and see what happens if they do not pay, complying
+only if goaded or presented with a legal writ. The principle of honor
+having been almost completely removed from the marketplace, debt
+acquires the halo of religion. (One might speak of a double theology,
+one for creditors and another for debtors.) It is no coincidence that
+the current phase of American debt imperialism has also been accompanied
+by the rise of the evangelical right, which has bucked the past two
+millennia of Christian thinking on the subject and enthusiastically
+embraced supply-side economics, taking the position that creating money
+and giving it to the rich is the most biblically appropriate way to
+bring about national prosperity. Perhaps the most ambitious theologian
+of the new creed was George Gilder, whose book *Wealth and Poverty*
+became a best seller in 1981, at the dawn of the Reagan revolution.
+Those who felt that money could not simply be created were mired in an
+old-fashioned, godless materialism, Gilder
+
+argued; they didn’t realize that just as God could create something out
+of nothing, his greatest gift to humanity was the ability to do so in
+the same fashion. And to do so was not hubristic, but in keeping with
+God’s intentions: The creation of money was a gift, a blessing, a
+channeling of grace; a promise, yes, but not one that can be fulfilled,
+even if the bonds are continually rolled over, because through faith
+(“in God we trust”) their value becomes real. “The United States,”
+Gilder writes, “must overcome the materialist fallacy: the illusion that
+resources and capital are essentially things, which can run out, rather
+than products of human will and imagination which in freedom are
+inexhaustible.” Such effusions inspired evangelists like Pat Robertson
+to declare supply-side economics “the first truly divine theory of
+money-creation.”
+
+This new breed of capitalist evangelicals failed to acknowledge that the
+vast majority of the money being “created” was in fact a product of
+deficit spending to fund the mushrooming US military, a practice that
+was avidly pursued by Reagan and that reached its pinnacle under George
+W. Bush. Furthermore, until China became our chief creditor, money was
+“borrowed” almost exclusively from
+
+West Germany, Japan, South Korea, and Saudi Arabia—all nations that were
+under US military protection. The “products of human will and
+imagination” were backed by material forces after all: not so much
+fields, factories, or even oil wells, but aircraft carriers and
+laser-guided missiles. All
+
+the more curious is Christian fundamentalists’ obsession with waging war
+on Iraq—which they often referred to, among themselves, as “Babylon”—the
+birthplace of the debt-forgiveness decree and the interest-free
+commercial economy.
+
+**Islamic world, Middle Ages**\
+ From the beginning, Islam had a positive view of commerce. (Muhammad
+himself had been begun his life as a merchant.) The prohibitions against
+usury did not mitigate the growth of commerce, or even the development
+of complex credit instruments. To the contrary, the early centuries of
+the caliphate saw an efflorescence of both. Credit instruments were so
+essential that traders tended to keep their wealth on deposit and make
+everyday transactions using checks (*sakk*) instead of coins. Checks
+were countersigned and transferred, and letters of credit (*suftaja*)
+traveled across the Indian Ocean and the Sahara. These promissory notes
+operated independently of the state (and the deals made with them were
+beyond the purview of government enforcement): They never became paper
+money, could not be used to pay taxes, and their value remained based
+almost entirely on trust and reputation. If a trader was wronged, he
+could appeal to the Islamic courts, but commissioning a
+
+poet to compose verses deriding the debtor would have a much greater
+effect.
+
+Networks of trust were largely responsible for the spread of Islam over
+the caravan routes of central Asia and the Sahara and across the Indian
+Ocean, which became the main conduit of world trade. Islam gained a
+toehold in trade emporia from Aden to the Spice Islands, largely because
+Islamic courts were perfectly suited to provide those ports with legal
+infrastructure: the means of establishing contracts, recovering debts,
+and creating a banking sector capable of redeeming or transferring
+letters of credit. The resultant level of trust between merchants in the
+great Malay entrepôt Malacca was legendary. The city had Swahili, Arab,
+Egyptian, Ethiopian, and Armenian quarters, as well as quarters for
+merchants from regions of India, China, and Southeast Asia. Yet it was
+said that its merchants shunned enforceable contracts, preferring to
+seal transactions with, as the saying went, “a handshake and a glance at
+heaven.”
+
+Money Bags
+----------
+
+How many times have we been told that the advent of virtual money, the
+dematerialization of cash into plastic and dollars into blips of
+electronic information, has brought us into an unprecedented financial
+world, completely uncharted territory? That very assumption made it easy
+for Goldman Sachs, AIG, and their cohorts to convince people that any
+effort to understand, much less regulate, their dazzling new financial
+instruments was futile. But the moment one casts matters on a broad
+historical scale, it becomes clear that there’s nothing fundamentally
+new about the reign of virtual money, which would be recognizable to
+ancient Mesopotamian bureaucrats and Islamic traders alike.
+
+The new global currency—the free-floating dollar—is rooted in military
+power even more firmly than before. Debt peonage continues to be the
+main principle of recruiting labor globally—either in the literal sense,
+in much of East Asia and Latin America, or in the subjective sense,
+whereby most of those working for wages or even salaries feel that they
+are doing so primarily to pay off interest-bearing loans. New
+transportation and communications technologies have made things
+
+easier for creditors: They can charge domestic laborers and factory
+workers thousands of dollars to be transported to distant countries
+where they are forced to work off their debt, lacking legal protections.
+The overarching institutions that have been created to regulate these
+activities—those whose cosmic scale echoes the divinely inspired
+authority of kings of the ancient Middle East and the church of the
+Middle Ages—do not protect debtors, but rather enforce the rights of
+creditors. They all operate on the principle that one has to pay one’s
+
+debts (unless one is the United States Treasury), since the prospect of
+default by any country is assumed to imperil the entire world monetary
+system. Joseph Addison described that fear of collapse, which acts to
+buttress the system, in his 1711 essay “Public Credit,” recounting a
+nightmare in which Britain’s national wealth has disappeared. “There was
+as great a change in the hill of money-bags, and the heaps of money, the
+former shrinking, and falling into so many empty bags, that I now found
+not above a tenth part of them had been filled with money,” he writes.
+
+> The rest that took up the same space, and made the same figure as the
+> bags that were really filled with money, had been blown up with air,
+> and called into my memory the bags full of wind, which Homer tells us
+> his Hero received as a present from Æolus. The great heaps of gold on
+> either side of the throne now appeared to be only heaps of paper, or
+> little piles of notched sticks, bound up together in bundles, like
+> Bath faggots.
+
+We need to understand what philosophers in the Middle Ages, from Italy
+to India to China, already understood perfectly well: Money is not a
+thing, and is certainly not a scarce resource. Money is a promise. And
+it is a promise we keep to those we value and break to those we do not.
+In Greece, Ireland, Portugal, and Spain, sovereign-debt default
+
+seems ever more likely. If it occurs, then what will happen? Certain
+promises will be kept, and others will be broken. As we learn from
+politicians every day, it is rarely possible to keep all promises
+exactly as one has made them. Today, in the United Kingdom, many
+politicians are saying, “I know I was elected on a solemn pledge not to
+raise tuition fees, but now that I’m in power I realize that was
+unrealistic. We will have to triple them.” What they in fact mean is, “I
+have decided that promises made by this government to repay bankers, at
+an agreed-upon interest rate, for money they fabricated, are more
+important than promises made to my own constituents.” And if promises
+made to legal abstractions are always to be given priority over promises
+made to what we still occasionally, whether fondly or cynically, call
+the people, we might well ask ourselves why our system of government is
+still deemed democracy.
+